Explaining Hayek's "The Use of Knowledge in Society"
One of the best economics articles ever written is often misunderstood.
Hayek's seminal essay, "The Use of Knowledge in Society," explores the fundamental economic problem of how society efficiently coordinates the use of dispersed knowledge. Published in 1945, this work reflects Friedrich Hayek's perspective as an Austrian economist and a key proponent of classical liberalism.
Hayek begins by highlighting the dispersed nature of knowledge in society, emphasizing that no single individual or centralized authority possesses all the information necessary to plan and allocate resources optimally. Instead, knowledge is widely dispersed among countless individuals, each possessing unique, localized knowledge of specific circumstances, preferences, and opportunities.
According to Hayek, the market mechanism plays a crucial role in harnessing this dispersed knowledge. By allowing individuals to freely exchange goods, services, and information, markets serve as a decentralized process of discovery and coordination. Prices, which emerge from voluntary interactions, encapsulate valuable information about the relative scarcity and demand for goods, guiding individuals' decision-making and resource allocation. With prices individuals are able to act “as-if” they had the relevant information needed to economize on all resources in the economy.
Hayek argues that central planning, which relies on a concentrated authority making decisions based on limited information, is inherently flawed. The planner lacks the comprehensive knowledge necessary to effectively allocate resources and respond to ever-changing conditions. In contrast, the decentralized market process enables individuals to adapt and respond to local knowledge, resulting in spontaneous order and more efficient resource allocation.
Many people misrepresent Hayek’s position because they ignore or misunderstand his explicit emphasis on tacit knowledge. The misrepresentation occurs because they treat all knowledge and information as something that is “objective” and capturable — such as the amount of oil in a container or date and time an event occurred. Framing knowledge and information as purely objective, they believe Hayek’s challenge to central planning can be solved by advances in technology. This interpretation of Hayek is wrong. As it completely ignores his emphasis on tacit knowledge playing a major role in economic decision making and by its nature inarticulable. Tacit knowledge is subjective, personal, and uncapturable by an observer. It is not measurable, nor can it be codified into simple rules and applied by others. Moreover, tacit knowledge is conditioned by local circumstances. The institutions of private property and prices create unique local circumstances where knowledge and information can be generated, through the discovery process of entrepreneurship, which otherwise would not exist. Making the problem of “the use of knowledge in society”, not one of mere practicality solved by technology and engineering, but an insurmountable problem of epistemology.
Hayek emphasizes the importance of competition in facilitating the discovery and dissemination of knowledge. Through competition, different individuals and firms explore and experiment with various approaches and solutions, leading to a process of trial and error. Successful methods are rewarded, while unsuccessful ones are abandoned, enabling the continuous improvement and innovation of products and processes.
Hayek acknowledges that markets are not perfect and can sometimes lead to inefficiencies or undesirable outcomes. However, he argues that these imperfections are relatively minor compared to the limitations of central planning, which tends to amplify errors, stifles individual initiative, and hampers the discovery and utilization of dispersed knowledge.
To conclude, Hayek's "The Use of Knowledge in Society" argues for the superiority of decentralized, market-based systems over central planning in efficiently allocating resources. By embracing the dispersed nature of knowledge and the power of voluntary exchange, societies can tap into the vast array of individual expertise and enable adaptive coordination, fostering prosperity and progress.
I would be interested in a considered Austrian response to this treatment of Hayek’s 1945 paper . . .
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=9h8bIIfIoR0
. . . which I will introduce as follows.
This video centers on Hayek’s definition of a solved Vienna Problem:
“The conditions which the solution of this optimum problem must satisfy have been fully worked out and can be stated best in mathematical form: put at their briefest, they are that the marginal rates of substitution between any two commodities or factors must be the same in all their different uses.”
Hayek’s reference to “marginal rates of substitution” would seem to take the availability of production and utility functions for granted as the boundary conditions for solving Mises’ calculation problem. (And, indeed, creating empirically meaningful production functions has been going on for a long time.)
Noting that “our only exogenous references are the same as Hayek’s” the authors of this video then locate your “tacit knowledge” in the shapes of production and utility tradeoffs:
“The plethora of physical and financial data needed to perform economic calculation is already there in the boundary conditions through which Hayek perceived the calculation problem.”
The interesting disconnect with Austrianism is that these guys go on to demonstrate the validity of their premises through desktop prototypes that perform artificial economic calculation, e.g.:
http://www.sfecon.com/YouTube%20Demo.xlsm
The point of view established here is that economic computation is simply what an unencumbered economy does, irrespective of anyone’s “insurmountable problem[s] of epistemology”. And, if there are such creatures as economists, then they should be distinguished by having created analogs to what this economic gizmo does.
As a point of further interest, one might consider that this intelligent economic robot has beguiled some potent practitioners of economic command:
https://onedrive.live.com/?authkey=%21AFs7Dqeqw1xjL6U&id=EA68D02ADD8A675D%211220&cid=EA68D02ADD8A675D&parId=root&parQt=sharedby&o=OneUp